July 2006
Marginalist Revolution
http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/margrev/margrev.htm
"In fact, the whole world may be looked upon as a vast general market made up of diverse special markets where social wealth is bought and sold. Our task then is to discover the laws to which these purchases and sales tend to conform automatically. To this end, we shall suppose that the market is perfectly competitive, just as in pure mechanics we suppose to start with, that machines are perfectly frictionless."
(Léon
worlds in space, that I believe I have performed for the explanations of men on earth.""On the following pages I submit to public judgement the result of twenty years of meditation. What a Copernicus succeeded in explaining of the relationships of
Gossen, Development of the Laws of Exchange among Men 1854: p.1)(Hermann Heinrich
"The conclusion to which I am ever more clearly coming is that the only hope of attaining a true system of Economics is to fling aside, once and for ever, the mazy and preposterous assumptions of the Ricardian School. Our English Economists have been living in a fool's paradise. The truth is with the French School, and the sooner we recognize this fact, the better it will be for the world."
Jevons, Theory of Political Economy, 1871: p.xliv-xlv).(William Stanley
"[Jevons's] success was aided even by his faults. For under the honest belief that Ricardo and his followers had rendered their account of the causes that determine value hopelessly wrong by omitting to lay stress on the law of satiable wants, he led many to think he was correcting great errors; whereas he was really only adding very important explanations."
Marshall, Principles of Economics, 1890: p.84-85).(Alfred
"If, instead of welcoming inquiry and criticism, the admirers of a great author accept his writings as authoritative, both in their excellences and in their defects, the most serious injury is done to truth. In matters of philosophy and science, authority has ever been the great opponent of truth. A despotic calm is usually the triumph of error. In the republic of the sciences, sedition and even anarchy are beneficial in the long run to the greatest happiness of the greatest number."
Jevons, Theory of Political Economy, 1871: p.275-6)(William Stanley
"In the closing quarter of the last century, great hopes were entertained by economists with regard to the capacity of economics to be made an "exact science". According to the view of the foremost theorists, the development of the doctrine of utility and value had laid the foundation of scientific economics in exact concepts, and it would soon be possible to erect upon the new foundation a firm structure of interrelated parts which, in definiteness and cogency, would be suggestive of the severe beauty of the mathematico-physical sciences. But this expectation has not been realized."
Moore, Economic Cycles,1914: p.84-85)(Henry L.
http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/margrev/margrevcont.htm
Contents:
(1) The Neoclassicals: Introduction
(A) Protagonists of the Marginalist Revolution
(B) Basic Elements of the Neoclassical Theory of Value
(C) The Neoclassical Family of Schools
(2) Phases of the Marginalist Revolution
(A) Scarcity and Utility in the Classical Schema
(B) The Franco-Italian Tradition: Subjective Scarcity
(C) The Holy Grail: Marginal Utility
(D) The Revolution of 1871-4.
(E) Consolidation: the Great Flood.
(F) Aftermath: the Great Drought.
(G) The Paretian Revival
(3)
http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/jevons.htm
English economist and logician whom, simultaneously with Carl
Menger and Léon Walras, launched the Marginalist Revolution of 1871-4 that gave birth to Neoclassical economics.Stanley Jevons (as he preferred to be called) was born in Liverpool on September 1, 1835, the ninth child of a family of prosperous iron merchants. However, the death of his mother in 1845 and the collapse of the family firm in 1848 circumscribed Jevons's opportunities. His early education was acquired at home, the Liverpool Mechanics Institute and finally at a preparatory school in London.
As a Unitarian (a liberal non-conformist Protestant sect), Jevons was legally barred from taking the traditional educational route through Oxford, Cambridge, etc. So, in 1852, Jevons entered University College London (UCL), a Benthamite institution that accepted non-conformists, to study chemistry, mathematics and logic. It was here that he came under the influence of the logician Augustus De Morgan. However, financial circumstance forced him to withdraw in his second year and accept a post as Assayer at the new Royal Mint in Sydney, Australia.
After arriving in Sydney in 1854, Jevons spent his spare time (and there was plenty of it) studying the climate, geography, geology and flora of Australia. He took daily meteorological observations and hobnobbed with the local scientific community. A local dispute over railway funding led Jevons to study up on economics. Jevons read Dionysus Lardner's 1850 book, Railway Economy, which contained a geometric treatment of demand and supply. It was this, more than anything else, that inspired Jevons to begin his investigations into a "mathematical approach" to economics.
After his father's death in 1855 and a bit of soul-searching, Jevons returned to London in 1859 and earned his B.A. in at UCL in 1860. His M.A. in Logic, Philosophy and Political Economy was acquired in 1862. In that same year, Jevons sent two papers to the British Association meetings at Oxford. The first discussed his ideas about how to introduce mathematical methods and subjective utility into economics (a version was later published in 1866). The second paper was a study of seasonal fluctuations in prices. In 1863, Jevons published a monograph computing the impact of the Australian and Canadian gold rushes on the general price level (here, he introduced a novel method of constructing price indexes using the geometric mean). None of these economic publications garnered much response, so he moved back to philosophy and logic.
In 1863, Jevons published his Pure Logic, wherein he improved the symbolic logic schema pioneered by George Boole and his teacher Augustus De Morgan. Jevons also introduced his own system of logic, the "substitution of similars" (restated in 1869). In essence, Jevons forwarded the idea that logical problems can be resolved exactly like algebraic equations just by stating the statements symbolically and then substituting elements with similar properties. For instance, "All men are mortal" and "Socrates is man" is resolved quickly by the algebra-like substitution of the common element in both statements ("man"), to yield the conclusion "Socrates is mortal". This may seem self-evident for simple syllogisms, but Jevons was convinced that more complex logical problems could be solved in this manner.
Jevons spent the next few years working as a tutor and part-time lecturer at Owens College in Manchester and Queen's College in Liverpool. It was during this time that he wrote his 1865 Coal Question, an alarmist treatise drawing attention to the imminent exhaustion of energy supplies. It was in here that the so-called "Jevons Paradox" was first posited, i.e. that an improvement in the efficiency of resource-use leads to an increase (rather than a decrease) in the use of that resource. The book sold well and was widely discussed in government circles. It brought a small degree of fame to the young Jevons. He followed this up with a series of insightful and popular papers on currency and coinage (later collected in his Investigations (1884)).
In 1866, Jevons was appointed Professor of Logic and Philosophy at Owens College and, soon after, he married Harriet Ann Taylor (no, not that one; this one was the daughter of a newspaper baron, the founder of the Manchester Guardian). Jevons returned to logic around this time, further developing the "logical alphabets" of Boolean schemata. Due to his power as a popularizer (e.g. 1870, 1876), many of Jevons's innovations continue today (e.g. the removal of subtraction and division, the inclusion of "both" in the disjunctive "either...or", etc.). As he hammered the symbolic method into shape, Jevons became particularly entranced by the way logical problems could be resolved by just repeatedly applying simple, mechanical rules. In 1870, he unveiled his famous "logical piano" at a Royal Society meeting -- a primitive, three-foot computer which solved logical calculations at superhuman speed via keys, pulleys and switches (see image). As he wrote:
"To the reader of the preceding paper it will be evident that mechanism is capable of replacing for the most part the action of thought required in the performance of logical deduction. Mental agency is required only in interpreting correctly the grammatical structure of the premises, and in gathering the purport of the reply... The machine is thus the embodiment of a true symbolic method or Calculus" (Jevons, 1870: p.517).
His research on logic was interrupted in 1870 when Fleeming Jenkin sent him a copy of his pamphlet on mathematical economics. Fearful of being upstaged, Jevons dashed off his Theory of Political Economy in 1871, expanding on the themes of his earlier 1866 paper and launching the Marginalist Revolution in the process. He began by outlining the principle of diminishing marginal utility and showed how it governed individual choice via the equimarginal principle.
In the context of a pure exchange economy, Jevons showed how this principle served as a foundation for a new and comprehensive theory of value. By combining two "laws" of exchange -- that every exchange must be mutually beneficial and that every portion must be exchanged at the same rate (his famous "Law of Indifference") -- Jevons came to the conclusion that a higgledy-piggledy exchange process (without price-taking behavior) will work its way necessarily to the market equilibrium. Several reviewers, most notably Francis Ysidro Edgeworth (1881), disputed this conclusion, arguing that the point at which exchange would cease was indeterminate. Although Jevons acknowledged that indeterminacy would arise if indivisible commodities were involved, he did not see the connection Edgeworth was trying to make between indeterminacy and the "degree of competition".
In his attempt to extend his theory to a production economy, Jevons introduced his disutility theory of labor supply (which later precipitated a debate over cost theory) and his time-dependent theory of capital (anticipating the Austrians). Although these ideas were individually groundbreaking, they were not very well-integrated with each other or the remainder of his theory.
Unbeknownst to Jevons, Carl Menger (1871) had just published a book expounding the same theory and, a little while later, Léon Walras (1874) presented his own version. The Marginalist Revolution had taken hold independently at three axes. Jevons got in contact with Walras in 1874 -- the latter recognized the former's claim to precedence, while the former recognized the latter's claim of independent discovery. They promised to join forces to perpetuate the new gospel but, for reasons not altogether clear, Jevons did a bit less than he promised to do. Despite the fact that both men traveled to each other's countries on several occasions, they never succeeding in meeting.
Soon after the publication of the Theory, Jevons grew gradually aware that, in fact, many other earlier writers -- such as Cournot and Gossen -- had anticipated many of his economic ideas. He was half-disappointed by this, but, at the same time, it confirmed his conviction that his theory was probably right. In his revolutionary zeal, Jevons had not withheld his punches, bitterly accusing the reigning (but moribund) Ricardian School -- particularly John Stuart Mill -- of seriously retarding the development of economics through "the noxious influence of authority" (Jevons, 1871: p.275). Contemporary Classical economists realized that Jevons was calling for subversion and responded accordingly, thereby inadvertently make his theory better known.
In 1874, Jevons published his masterpiece of scientific methodology, Principles of Science, wherein he presented his theory of scientific inference. Following up on De Morgan and Whewell, Jevons took aim at the empirical approach of John Stuart Mill. Induction, Jevons claimed, "is simply an inverse employment of deduction." (1874: p.viii). While championing the hypothetico-deductive method, Jevons recognized that it yielded, at best, only partial knowledge. In order to make a "perfect" induction, Jevons argued, it is necessary to list in the premises all the possible cases or instances from which the empirical conclusion can be derived. But, in most matters, such a complete enumeration cannot be done in practice. As a result, Jevons's argued, "general laws" are at best only "probable". He introduced, in the process, an epistemological theory of probability, arguing that probabilities are mere "measures of ignorance" or, as he liked to call it, measures of "rational expectation" (i.e. reasonable belief).
Jevons's "inverse probability" theory of induction argues that we can deduce the "most probable" cause of an event by examining all possible hypotheses (all equally likely), deducing all possible consequences from them, comparing these consequences with the facts and then picking the hypothesis which is most likely to yield that event:
"If an event can be produced by any one of a certain number of different causes, all equally probable a priori, the probabilities of the existence of these causes as inferred from the event, are proportional to the probabilities of the event as derived from these causes. (Jevons, 1874: p. 242-243).
Jevons's method is merely an application of Bayes's Theorem, e.g. suppose P(x | A) = p, P(x | B) = q and P(x | C) = r are the conditional probabilities of consequence x from hypothetical causes A, B and C. So, we can evaluate the hypotheses by calculating P(A | x) = p/(p + q + r), P(B | x) = q/(p+q+r) and P(C | x) = r/(p+q+r) and choosing the one with the greatest probability. This seems straightforward enough. However, the idea that inductive knowledge was mere probability -- David Hume's old saw -- flew in the face of the scientific consensus of the time and caused a bit of an uproar.
In 1875 and 1878, Jevons read two papers before the British Association which expounded his famous "sunspot theory" of the business cycle. Digging through mountains of statistics of economic and meteorological data, Jevons argued that there was a connection between the timing of commercial crises and the solar cycle.
The basic chain of events was that variations in sunspots affect the power of the sun's rays, influencing the bountifulness of harvests and thus the price of corn which, in turn, affected business confidence and gave rise to commercial crises. Jevons changed his story several times (e.g. he replaced his European harvest-price-crisis logic with an Indian harvest-imports-crisis channel).
However flimsy his explanations, Jevons believed that the periodicity of the solar cycle and commercial crises -- approximately 10.5 years, by his calculations -- was too coincidental to be dismissed. Needless to say, all this was a bit on the cranky end and, ultimately, the statistics did not bear him out. Nonetheless, it remains a significant piece of work as this was perhaps the first time that the phenomenon of the business cycle was identified. Economists had long been aware that business activity had its ups and downs, but not that they necessarily followed any regular pattern. They generally believed that "crises" arrived haphazardly, punctuating the smooth advance of the economy at irregular intervals. Jevons was perhaps the first economist to argue that the phases of business activity had a regular, measurable and predictable periodicity.
Although Jevons had renounced Benthamite utilitaranism as a workable political or ethical philosophy in his 1871 Theory (as distinct from the use of the utility concept to illustrate the "simple and restricted" problem of economic exchange), his work on social philosophy and public policy (1879, 1882, 1883) resurrected the theme. Once again, he targeted John Stuart Mill -- particularly his distinction between "higher" and "lower" pleasures. Jevons did not deny, to use his famous example, that a public library increased "social utility" more than a race-track, but he denied that its superiority lay in Mill's distinction between a "high quality" pleasure (reading) and a "low quality" pleasure (betting). Instead, Jevons argued, libraries yield a higher quantity of social utility than racetracks. Races yield intense but momentary pleasure. Reading is longer-lasting and more fruitful. Thus, measured over a lifetime, reading yields a greater quantity of pleasure than betting. Jevons also denounced Mill for failing to incorporate Spencer's evolutionism into utilitarian doctrine.
Jevons's economic policy positions, although broadly in line with a laissez-faire attitude, fall short of being doctrinaire. Where government policy can increase happiness in one segment of the population without diminishing that of another, it should be pursued -- albeit with caution to ensure that all indirect effects are accounted for. Trade unions, to take his famous example, fail on this criteria as their gains often come at the "expense" of consumers and non-union workers.
In 1872, Jevons was elected a Fellow of the Royal Society and, in 1876, he was appointed Professor of Political Economy at University College London. Disliking lecturing and plagued by ill-health, he retired in 1880. Against his doctor's warnings, Jevons continued swimming regularly, his favorite recreational activity. In 1882, he drowned at sea off Devon. An avid book-collector, Jevons left behind a library of several thousand volumes and (anticipating a future world-wide shortage), an enormous stock of blank writing paper.
The impact of Jevons on economics can hardly be exaggerated. As the father of Neoclassical economics, his legacy is secure. However, in some ways, he stopped short of the mark. Jevons could have gone further by connecting his insights in pure exchange into a wider theory incorporating production, capital, money and the business cycle in a more systematic and consistent manner that would have knocked the Ricardian School completely out of the picture. Had he not died so young, Jevons might yet have done so, but the next economics treatise he was working on (published posthumously in 1905), did not really seem to go in that ambitious direction. As such, by the time of his death, the Marginalist Revolution was still in its insurrectionist phase. It was still a tentative proposition rather than a firmly-set and integrated system, a scientific hypothesis but not quite yet a science.
Strangely enough, the task of completion was taken up by Alfred Marshall, whom Jevons initially thought a disciple but ultimately turned out to be a rival. Marshall's Neoclassical system, a woolly compromise between the Ricardian and Jevonian theories, was to rule Anglo-Saxon economics for the next half-century.
Jevons's considerably more radical vision was carried on by a small group of followers -- notably Francis Ysidro Edgeworth and Philip H. Wicksteed. In the 1930s, as the Marshallian consensus collapsed, Jevonian radicalism re-emerged in Britain (esp. at the L.S.E.), this time hand-in-hand with the Austrian and Lausanne theories.
Major Works of W.S. Jevons
"A Comparison of the Land and Railway Policy of New South Wales" and "The Public Lands of New South Wales", Empire, 1857
"Notice of a General Mathematical Theory of Political Economy", 1862, Report of BAAS
"On the Study of Periodic Commercial Fluctuations", 1862, Report of BAAS
A Serious Fall in the Value of Gold Ascertained, and its social effects set forth , 1863.
Pure Logic, or the science of quality apart from quantity
The Coal Question: An inquiry concerning the progress of the nation and the probable exhaustion of our coal mines
"On the Variation of Prices, and the Value of the Currency since 1782", 1865, JSS of London
"On the Frequent Autumnal Pressure in the Money Market, and the Action of the Bank of England", 1866, JSS of London
"Brief Account of a General Mathematical Theory of Political Economy", 1866, JSS of London.
An Introductory Lecture on the Importance of Diffusing a Knowledge of Political Economy
"On Coal: Its importance in manufactures and trade", 1867, Science Lectures for the People.
"On the Analogy between the Post-Office, Telegraphs and other systems of Conveyance of the United Kingdom", 1867, Trans Manchester SS
A Lecture on the Trades' Societies: their objects and policy, 1868
Lecture on the Probable Exhaustion of our Coal Mines
"On the International Monetary Convention and the Introduction of an International Currency into this kingdom", 1868, Trans of Manchester SS
"On the Condition of the Metallic Currency of the United Kingdom, with reference to the question of international coinage", 1868, JSS of London
The Substitution of Similars: the true principle of reasoning, derived from a modification of Aristotle's dictum, 1869.
"The Pressure of Taxation", 1869 (gov. report, publ, 1905).
"The Value of Gold", 1869, JSS of London.
"On the Work of the Society in Connection with the Questions of the Day", 1869, Trans of Manchester SS.
"Opening Address of the President of Section F of the British Association for the Advancement of Science", 1870, Trans of BAAS and JSS of London
"On the Mechanical Performance of Logical Inference", 1870, Philos Trans of Royal Society
On Industrial Partnership, 1870
Elementary Lessons in Logic
The Match Tax
The Theory of Political Economy
"The Progress of the Mathematical Theory of Political Economy, with an explanation of the principles of the theory", 1874, Trans of Manchester SS and JRSS.
"Théorie mathématique de l'échange: Question de priorité. Correspondence entre M. Jevons, Professeur à Manchester et M. Walras, Professeur à Lausanne", 1874, Journal des économistes
Principles of Science: A treatise on logic and scientific method , 1874.
"On the Progress of the Coal Question", 1875, Trans of BAAS
"Post-Office Telegraphs and their Financial Results", 1875, Fortnightly Review
Money and the Mechanism of Exchange, 1875.
"An Ideally Perfect System of Currency", 1875
"Influence of the Sun-Spot Period on the Price of Corn", 1875, Nature
"Cruelty to Animals: A study in sociology", 1876, Fortnightly Review
"On the United Kingdom Alliance and its Prospects of Success", 1876, Trans Manchester SS
"The Future of Political Economy", 1876, Fortnightly Review
Primer of Logic , 1876.
"Cram", 1877, Mind
"The Silver Question", 1877, London Banker's Magazine
"John Stuart Mill's Philosophy Tested", I (1877), II & III (1878), IV (1879), Contemporary Review
"Professor Stanley Jevons and Mr. Mill", 1878, Academy
Primer of Political Economy, 1878
"The Periodicity of Commercial Crises and its Physical Explanation", 1878, Trans BAAS
"Commercial Crises and Sun-Spots", 1878, Nature
"Remarks on the Statistical use of the Arithmometer", 1878, JRSS
"Methods of Social Reform", I (1878), II (1879), Contemporary Review
"Sun-spots and Commercial Crises", 1879, Nature
Four Essays on John Stuart Mill's Philosophy Tested, 1879
Studies in Deductive Logic
"Postal Notes, Money Orders and Bank Cheques", 1880, Contemporary Review
"Preface", 1880, in L. Cossa, Guide to the Study of Political Economy.
"Richard Cantillon and the Nationality of Political Economy", 1881, Contemporary Review
"Bimetallism", 1881, Contemporary Review
"The Rationale of Free Public Libraries", 1881, Contemporary Review
"Review of Edgeworth's Mathematical Psychics", 1881, Mind (also PDF version)
"The Solar Commercial Cycle", 1882, Nature
"Married Women in Factories", 1882, Contemporary Review
The State in Relation to Labour, 1882.
Methods of Social Reform
Investigations in Currency and Finance
Studies in Deductive Logic
Letters and Journal of W. Stanely Jevons
Pure Logic and Other Minor Works
The Principles of Economics
Papers and Correspondence of W. Stanley Jevons
Writings on Economics
Resources on W. Stanley Jevons
HET Page: Marginalist Revolution: Phase 1871-74, Jevons's Theory of Exchange, Jevons's Theory of Capital, Climate Theories of the Cycle, the Anglo-American Marginalists
William Stanley Jevons Homepage by Bert Mosselmans, including:
"Jevons's Life" by Bert Mosselmans
"Bibliography of Jevons" by Bert Mosselmans
"References for Jevons", secondary resources compiled by Bert Mosselmans
"Introduction to W.S. Jevons, Collected Economic Writings" by Bert Mosselmans and Michael V. White, incl. Biblioraphy of Primary and Secondary works, Preface and Chapter 1 of Theory of Political Economy (1871) (pdf - large) (website of Collected Economic Writings)
Image of Jevons's "Logical Piano", 1870, from Philos Trans of Royal Society
"Review of Jevons's Coal Question" 1866, Quarterly Review (repr. Living Age)
"Review of Jevons's Theory of Political Economy", by S.N. (Simon Newcomb) 1872, North American Review
"Note" - a review of Jevons" by Alfred Marshall, 1874, Academy
"A New Standard of Value", by Walter Bagehot, 1875, The Economist
"Review of Jevons's Principles of Science", 1874, New Englander and Yale Review
"Review of Jevons's Principles of Science", 1875, Atlantic Monthly
"Review of Jevons's "Influence of the Sun-Spot Period"" by J.A. Church, 1876, The Galaxy
"Review of Jevons's Money and Mechanism of Exchange" by J.A. Church, 1876, The Galaxy
"Sun-Spots and Financial Panics" by Richard Anthony Proctor, 1880, Scribner's
"William Stanley Jevons: Obituary Notice" by R.H. [Harley] in Proceedings of the Royal Society of London, 1883, Vol. 35, p.i-xii.
"The Education of Professor Jevons", 1883, The Century
"The New Political Economy", 1886, The Century
"Review of Jevons's Pure Logic", 1891, New Englander and Yale Review
"Jevons's Economic Work", by Philip H. Wicksteed, 1905, Economic Journal, Vol. 15, Issue 59 (September), p.432-6. (PDF version)
"Review of Jevons's Theory, Pareto's Manuel and Marshall's Principles" by François Simiand, 1909, L'année sociologique, Ann. 11
"Review of Jevons's Theory of Political Economy", by Allyn A. Young, 1912, AER
"William Stanley Jevons" by R.D. Collinson Black New Palgrave, 1987 (PDF version)
"Jevons as an Economic Theorist" by Terry Peach, from New Palgrave, 1987 (PDF version)
"Reproduction and Scarcity: Hidden Agenda of the Marginal Revolution" by Bert Mosselmans, 1998, Guest Editorial HES
"Biography of W.S. Jevons" by P.L. Heath
Jevons Family Papers at John Rylands University Library, Manchester
Contributions from Logicians: Part I, from Richard Whately to William Stanley Jevons by Stanley N. Burris, 2001 (PDF)
W.S. Jevons entry at MacTutor History of Mathematics Archive.
"Jevons's Method of Inverse Probability" by Prof. Uchii at Kyoto
Jevons's Page at Britannica.com
Jevons Page at McMaster
Jevons Page at Akamac
Jevons Page at Melbourne
Jevons Page at Laura Forgette
"Logic Machines" at Maxmon.com
"W.S. Jevons" at Philosophonlexicon (in German)
Marginalist Revolution: Jevons
July 12, 2006